Showing posts with label economic policies. Show all posts
Showing posts with label economic policies. Show all posts

Thursday, August 25, 2011

"Bring on more and stronger earthquakes! It would be good for the economy!"

Nobel Prize-winning economist Paul Krugman was recently spoofed as having made such a suggestion:
People on twitter might be joking, but in all seriousness, we would see a bigger boost in spending and hence economic growth if the earthquake had done more damage.
It turns out those words were definitely not written by Paul Krugman.

However, Krugman has made several comments virtually identical to them.

"Ghastly as it may seem to say this, the (9/11 Twin Towers) terror attack -- like the original day of infamy, which brought an end to the Great Depression -- could even do some economic good. . . . Now, all of a sudden, we need some new office buildings. . . ." (New York Times, 14 September 2001)

"Think about World War II, right? That was actually negative social product spending, and yet it brought us out [of the Depression]." (CNN Global Public Square, 12 August 2011)

"If we discovered that space aliens were planning to attack and we needed a massive buildup to counter the space alien threat and really inflation and budget deficits took secondary place to that, this slump would be over in 18 months. And then if we discovered, oops, we made a mistake, there aren't any aliens, we'd be better [off]." (Same CNN article/broadcast; note that the actual video where these comments appear begins at about 13:35 into the video in the article.)

If a Nobel Prize-winning economist can make these kinds of comments with a straight face, it should not surprise us when "regular" citizens suggest "solutions" to our economic difficulties similar to those Krugman dishes out on a regular basis. (In the referenced New York Times column, for example, Krugman wrote, "[T]he attack opens the door to some sensible recession-fighting measures. For the last few weeks there has been a heated debate among liberals over whether to advocate the classic Keynesian response to economic slowdown, a temporary burst of public spending. . . . Now it seems that we will indeed get a quick burst of public spending, however tragic the reasons.")

Check out this brief, well-done video about The Broken Window Fallacy--a fallacy first noted by Frédéric Bastiat in 1850:



For a further nuanced discussion of the limitations of The Broken Window Fallacy (because there is a point at which one does want to see some broken windows!), please read the Wikipedia article on the subject, and especially Section 2.2, Limitations. . . . But keep reading through 2.3, The opportunity cost of war and 2.4, The cost of special interests and government.

Kind of mind-blowing!

Friday, April 09, 2010

Tax cuts v. tax cuts (Econoclasts, Part V)

#6 in an ongoing series on Brian Domitrovic's Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution and Restored American Prosperity. First post in the series: Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution, Intro. Previous post: Supply-Side Economics: What is it? (Econoclasts, Part IV)



I concluded my last post with an extremely brief summary of the solution proposed by the supply-side economists to the economic problems suffered by the United States in the 1970s. To wit: stabilize the dollar and cut taxes. If you want people to work, you need to incentivize them. And to incentivize them, you can't just cut any taxes or offer just any tax relief. The supply-siders were very explicit about this. To get people back to work and the economy back into a productive mode, government leaders had to cut the marginal tax rates--the tax that income-earners pay on their "next dollar of income"--the edge, the margin (p. 290).

It took me a while to understand what Domitrovic and the supply-siders were saying. There are at several issues at work, here. And they have to do, primarily, with incentives.

As Robert Bartley explained in a Wall Street Journal article, to encourage growth, you have to reduce taxes at the margins. Reducing taxes anywhere else--or, as President Ford's administration did (and so many others have done since), offering "rebates" or special bounties from the government (remember the $300 per person tax rebate offered by the federal government to low- and middle-income taxpayers via the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008?): such "backward-looking windfalls" don't change basic incentives. They don't encourage recipients to go to work and earn more money or invest for future productivity. Such windfalls merely encourage a (relatively minor) one-time spending spree or--as I'm told happened quite a bit in 2008--they provide a means for over-extended consumers to pay down some of the debt they have already contracted.

The greatest Keynesian verity in the realm of taxation is that tax cuts raise "aggregate demand." This is why tax rebates, in the Keynesian mindset, are legitimate. Put money in people's pockets, and they will spend it, the logic goes, to the extent that people have a "marginal propensity to consume."

--p. 200

As we noted in The Terrible 1970s, Part II, however, people in the '70s and early '80s were already spending at prodigious levels. The high rate of inflation ensured that kind of behavior. People didn't need more stimulus to spend. They needed stimulus to save and to invest for the future.

As John Paul Roberts argued in "The Breakdown of the Keynesian Model," an article he wrote in 1978, "rebates would probably cause people to work less, since, given the high marginal rates, giving up extra work was virtually painless from a financial perspective. If people were simply given more money through a rebate, they might cut back on work, because the last work they were doing was barely paying anyway" (p. 200).

And, as Robert Bartley also argued: the government had to start looking at changing long-term behaviors.
A rebate . . . was . . . nil or counterproductive in its [long-term] economic effects. Indexing the [tax] code for inflation or cutting marginal rates, however, promised a different outcome. These moves foretold changes in the ways people organized their economic activity, and the outcome would be growth.

--p. 124


In the '70s and early '80s, "taxes were so arranged as to make one's next activity virtually unremunerative. . . . With marginal rate cuts, there would be incentive for individuals to go ahead with new economic activity." Reduced marginal rates increase the rewards for working and for taking risks by investing one's capital for future returns, "and higher rewards produce more effort and more economic activity" (p. 290). Conversely, "If taxes were cut at the margin, the price of not choosing to take advantage of an economic opportunity would rise" (p. 200; emphasis added).

While we're on the subject, let me comment: the supply-siders were not only concerned about where taxes were to be cut, they also noted that taxes had to be cut on a long-term basis. "[T]emporary tax changes will at most move activity around from one [tax] period to another. For stimulus, you need to change future incentives, [which means] the tax cut has to be permanent," wrote Bartley (p. 290).

And one final comment about taxes--something Domitrovic did not emphasize but that struck me as I read his book. It has to do with . . .

A Bias in Terminology

Throughout the book, Domitrovic speaks, and the supply-siders he quotes speak, of capital investments and financial and productive assets. As I wrote in The Terrible 1970s, Part II, the supply-siders recognized a contrast between investing with an eye to future production and investing in tangible assets and "stuff"--a future- vs. past-orientation.

And then, suddenly, I ran across a phrase I've heard often while doing or reviewing my taxes, but that I had not thought of during all the discussion of capital investments and future-orientation. Domitrovic mentions a proposal by Democratic Representative William Brodhead of Michigan in March 1981 to bring "an end to the distinction between wage and investment income--'earned and unearned income' " (p. 225).

Oh, wow! That's right!

I sat there, stunned. Can you imagine a more negative characterization for the return on an investment in future productivity? "Unearned income." "Unearned income" is a form of stealing, isn't it? What right does someone have to hang onto income they haven't earned?

Now, the wages one earns through investing one's time in one's own labor . . . now, that's legitimate. That's "earned." But you want to risk your money by purchasing equipment or investing in the labor of someone who has an unproven idea for a new business (start-up capital, risk capital, venture capital)? If you make money from that kind of investment, that's "unearned."

Another biased term: "passive" vs. "active" income. Very much the same kind of distinction: one has to do with rental income you might receive on a building you paid to have built. That's "passive income." Totally different from "active income" which you earn either by your direct labor or by your direct participation in a business. Marxists refer to people who receive such passive income as "rentiers" . . . with the implication that they play no productive role in the economy but are mere parasites.

Kind of negative! But where would we be if they were unwilling to live below their means, aggregate their capital, and put it to use through investment in potential productive enterprise?

We need merely look back to the 1970s and early 80s to see where we would be. Recall the story of U.S. Steel (The Terrible 1970s, Part II, Item #6). Without appropriate investment, we’re looking at massive unemployment.

As Domitrovic writes (p. 7):
It was no accident that during [the 1970s and early '80s] Bill Gates could get his company out of the garage only by signing a contract with IBM. If you did not have a lifeline to the biggest, richest, most established companies, like IBM, you could forget about raising capital. With marginal income-tax rates upwards of 70 percent, there was no such thing as venture capital.

Tuesday, April 06, 2010

Supply-Side Economics: What is it? (Econoclasts, Part IV)

#5 in an ongoing series on Brian Domitrovic's Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution and Restored American Prosperity. First post in the series: Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution, Intro. Previous post: The Terrible 1970s, Part II (Econoclasts, Part III)



The ruling orthodoxy amongst government economists worldwide, pretty much from the 1930s and, mostly, even until today, is what is known as Keynesianism (CANE-zee-en-izm; after John Maynard Keynes [CANES])). Keynes had taught that unemployment and inflation are inverse twins: when unemployment is high, you can expect little if any pressure toward higher prices, i.e., price inflation will be low to nonexistent. Indeed, you may experience deflation--in which prices fall. Conversely, when there is little unemployment (i.e., when most people are employed), you can expect a serious trend toward higher prices, i.e., price inflation.

With these observations in mind, Keynes proposed some policies for governments to pursue. Most particularly, when economic activity falls and unemployment rises, governments need to step in and increase demand for goods and services. They can do this by means of "fiscal stimulus"--primarily tax cuts and/or deficit spending--and/or through "monetary policy"--reducing interest rates and/or increasing money supply (i.e., inflating the currency). As Domitrovic puts it,
In the Keynesian teaching, inflation is tolerable because it means that people are out there spending money vigorously, demanding, pushing up prices in the name of growth. Taxes, in turn, take money from people who might save it rather than spend it, and then give that money to the one entity that will assuredly spend it: government.
Keynesian economics was de rigueur in the '60s and early '70s. Very few economists of any note were willing to question it.

By the mid-1970s, however, it was becoming obvious to all that Keynesian orthodoxy was unworkable. The United States was suffering ever higher unemployment together with ever increasing price inflation. Meanwhile, the government was spending at unprecedented levels beyond its income.

And, withal, there was widespread talk of doom, of permanent stagflation and “the necessity of adjusting to 'diminished expectations.'

It was in this context, then, that several key players--almost all relatively young--came forward to question the reigning orthodoxy.

And they were soon labeled “supply-siders”--a name originally attached to them with derision, but, ultimately, adopted by proponents as a badge of honor.

Why "supply-side"?

Catch the juxtaposition with (or against) Keynesianism. Keynes had taught that demand--not enough buyers--was the key economic problem.

The "supply-siders" said there was plenty of demand . . . if only the government would get out of the way and permit investors to supply what the economy needs: most particularly, investment capital.

I mentioned that Keynes had taught, at least at one point in his career, that the cause of economic recessions--or depressions--is a lack of demand, i.e., a lack of people willing to spend money. And so governments need to use fiscal (taxing and spending) and monetary (interest rates and money supply) policies to increase demand.

“Supply-side” economics also speaks of fiscal and monetary policies, but approaches them from almost the exact opposite direction. According to “supply-side” economics,
Inflation [i]s by its very nature an inducement not to work and produce, but to consume and demand, to spend one's dollars before they [devalue]. . . . If inflation [is] conquered, people [will] seek to gain income through work and investment, because in the context of stable prices, income holds its value. [However, note well!] work and investment [will] be for naught if new income [is] then confiscated by taxes. Hence, a monetary policy aimed at maintaining stable prices [must be] coupled with a tax policy aimed at stimulating personal initiative . . . in order to cure stagflation.

--p. 15

The two leading supply-side economists, Robert Mundell and Arthur Laffer,
said that the stagflation crisis . . . had originated with government. . . . First, the government had taken to destabilizing the means of exchange--the dollar--by printing it with abandon. This was the origin of inflation. Second, the government had jacked up tax rates, particularly on income that people earned as they got richer. This brought about disincentives to work and poisoned the well of capital formation. Unemployment was the necessary result.

The solution to the problem [they suggested] was clear: stabilize the dollar and cut taxes.

--p. 10

Okay. Stabilize the dollar and cut marginal [highest-end] tax rates. These, says Domitrovic, are the cornerstones of supply-side economics.

Next time: Tax cuts v. tax cuts

Monday, April 05, 2010

The Terrible 1970s, Part II (Econoclasts, Part III)

#4 in an ongoing series on Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution and Restored American Prosperity. First post in the series: Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution, Intro. Previous post: The Terrible 1970s (Econoclasts, Part II)



--Continued from The Terrible 1970s (Econoclasts, Part II).

. . . With capital investments being taxed at such high rates, people who had money to invest did the only reasonable thing they could do in such circumstances: they invested in tangible assets rather than stocks and bonds. Put another way, the '70s saw . . .

5. A preference for "stuff" over saving.

We could go into more detail but let me quote just one section from Econoclasts:
[C]onsumerism was rampant in the 1970s. Sales of all sorts of things, useful goods and especially novelties such as recreational vehicles, were robust in the Carter years. Given inflation, this was only logical. If one bought immediately on getting paid, one exchanged money for goods. If instead one saved one's pay, that money largely evaporated. Savings could not reasonably be held in bank accounts, whose rates lagged behind inflation. . . . Savings could be put in gold, commodities, and land, and indeed they were. But as always these were tricky investments, with land having an excise tax attached to boot. Saving money became a fine art, an option foreclosed to the masses. So the masses spent.
--pp. 180-181

6. A preference for commodities and "stuff" over capital investment.

Domitrovic provides many examples of this point, but one particularly caught my eye: the story of U.S. Steel. That's partially because of a book I read several years ago that suggested the decline of the U.S. steel industry occurred because the American manufacturers were unwilling to adopt mini-mill technology, a low-cost, efficient technology that their competitors from overseas were using, first to produce pig iron, then rebar, and then, slowly, up the chain of quality until, finally, they could produce even high-end steel. The author of the book I read referred to "low-end disruptive" technology and suggested that the American steel industry was kind of "caught unawares."

Domitrovic suggested something else was at work. The federal government's tax policies made it uneconomical to invest in capital improvements. It made more sense to put one's resources elsewhere.
In the 1970s, U.S. Steel declined to make the big capital investments that technological innovation had made necessary in the race to keep up with its competition, especially foreign competition.

In particular, U.S. Steel chose not to buy the (expensive) basic oxygen process (BOP) furnaces and continuous casting machines for its plants. The storied Homestead Works near Pittsburgh went to its grave in 1987 having never replaced its Carnegie-era open-hearth furnaces with a "BOP shop," nor its ingot molds with a caster. This had easily made Homestead irrelevant in the international steel market by 1980. But by that date, U.S. Steel had found a better use for the capital it could have spent on steelmaking machines. It set aside $6 billion to acquire Marathon Oil, whose petroleum reserves increased in value with inflation. Had U.S. Steel bought capital equipment with that $6 billion, it would have been killed by taxes and inflation. Thus did the company, soon to be called "USX," forsake steel for oil.

After 1982, when the [Marathon Oil] transaction cleared, approximately 160,000 steel workers lost their jobs. This was precisely the future that began to worry workers in the early 1970s in Buffalo and Lackawanna, New York, Lake Erie towns that were home to massive Bethlehem Steel plants, today as shuttered as Homestead.
--pp. 133-134
Domitrovic provides other examples of this shift from capital investments into tangibles. He describes General Electric's temptation to abandon "manufacturing in such areas as power generation, engines, and medical devices" in favor of "the small natural-resources segment of its business portfolio" that was producing "exceptional profits" (p. 152).
In the late 1970s, the commodity play appeared a plausible strategy. In 1978, for example, GE's natural resources business accounted for 5 percent of the total sales of the company, yet 15 percent of its profits.
--p. 218
GE's main competitor, Westinghouse, actually pursued this strategy. "In the 1980s, Westinghouse decided to wind down its core competency, nuclear power, and gobble up land out west, as if it were a time for survivalism" (p. 259). Once inflation was slain--just at the time that Westinghouse was moving into tangible assets--that particular strategy turned out to be counterproductive. GE surged ahead while Westinghouse "edged to the brink of bankruptcy in the late 1980s and 1990s and was forced to reverse-merge into a shell" (ibid.).

Domitrovic tells the story of the experience that convinced Congressman Jack Kemp, during his freshman year in Congress, to seek a major reduction in capital gains taxes. Kemp said he saw a help-wanted sign on a machine shop in his district. It included an unusual requirement of anyone who was to be a successful candidate. He had to be able to "Bring own lathe." Clearly, the machine shop owner didn't want to take the risk--or pay the price--to buy equipment for his employees. He figured it would be a bad investment: "I'm willing to hire you, but I'm not willing to buy the tools you'll need to do your job."

For me, one of the most striking concepts having to do with investment in commodities v. capital equipment arose from the research and thinking of a Northwestern Mutual Life Insurance Company economist. Domitrovic says Harvey Wilmeth "discovered a Federal Reserve publication that detailed the 'balance sheet' of the nation." According to this document, by the late '70s, more than half of all assets in the United States were "tangible assets--hard assets such as real estate, collectibles, commodities, and consumer durables."

Domitrovic says this is, was, and, from a forward-looking perspective, ought to be, abnormal. "Under ordinary circumstances, financial assets [stocks and bonds should] dwarf tangible assets in value" (pp. 216-217).

Why?
"Stuff" is what has already been produced. "Securities" or "financial assets"--stocks and bonds--are claims on what will be produced in the future. The ratio of stuff to securities is a measure, therefore, of confidence in the economic future. If the ratio is getting higher, as it was in the late 1970s, the message is that expectations are declining about the future production of stuff.
--p. 217; emphasis added
Or put the other way around: If a nation is to have a future, if it is to have positive future expectations, then it ought to have--it needs to have--a greater investment in capital stock than commodities.
Wilmeth realized that the taxes and inflation of the 1970s had increased the cost of holding financial but not tangible assets. Because taxes in general were . . . income taxes, and because inflation buoyed the value of things already produced or in the ground, the rise in income-tax rates along with inflation in the 1970s had led to a tremendous move out of stocks and bonds and into the stuff that presently existed. . . .[F]uture stuff . . . cannot be produced without investments in financial assets. The shift into tangibles thus prefigured a decline in production.
--p. 217; emphasis added
Financial assets--stocks, bonds, mortgages--are bets on people being productive in the future. They have nothing to do with the past. . . . For the market for financial assets to improve, there must be a clear reason for businesses and individuals to believe that there will be stable money, low taxes, and beneficial but spare regulations as new economic initiatives are undertaken.
--p. 291
If you want people investing for future productivity, you can't disincentivize them by taxing such behavior so that it makes more sense for them to buy non-productive "stuff" than to pay for productive assets in hopes that they might produce profits in the future. (I hope I'm not sounding like too much of a broken record. Remember my post on March 14th: More on taxes and tax avoidance . . . and prosperity? I quoted a speaker who noted that politicians understand how taxes work as incentives (or disincentives) in other areas of life: "We want to decrease the number of people who smoke. Let's raise taxes on cigarettes." Why don't they understand that the same thinking applies to such issues as income and investment?)

7. Resource shortages or scarcities.

At a conference held in May 1974 by the American Enterprise Institute, Robert Mundell
provided a table showing commodities that had risen in price as much as or more than oil in recent years, among them cotton, rice, and wheat, with sugar beating oil's price increase by a factor of three. . . . Since the United States in particular had given up on mooring the dollar to gold in any credible way in the 1960s, and since the convention up to that point had been for the world's currencies to be priced in relation to the dollar, this was the result: "Confidence in currencies in general declined and a shift out of money and financial assets commenced. . . . [Soon] the prices of metals, foods and minerals more than doubled. Shortages of beef, sugar and grains appeared, but gold and oil led to the most dramatic 'crises' and received the most attention from the public."
--p. 108

What was happening? With inflation running rampant, buyers were seeking to acquire everything they could as soon as possible (while their money still had value) . . . while producers were motivated to slow supply as much as possible to get the best (future) price.

8. Terrible unemployment.

We've already told the story of steel workers being thrown out of work.
Inflation plus a progressive tax code that made it impossible to have two things simultaneously: a job and pay. You can have a job, but if you've militated for real pay, the employer would run out of cash and thus have to look for a less labor-intensive business to go into and make the playoffs. Inflation did not cure unemployment in the 1970s; it caused it.
--p. 152
Before 1979, bracket creep combined with inflation had encouraged vigilance on the part of wage earners. They had to get a COLA-plus in order simply to get a COLA. The inflation that came in 1979 and 1980 intensified this requirement beyond all hope. Workers from across the income spectrum were now at best breaking even against inflation and taxes. After the 26 percent inflation of 1979-80, raises had to be in the 30 percent-50 percent range in order to reach par.

If an employee got such a raise, it was a brilliant coup. But it was devastating to his employer. To grant employees raises that kept up with inflation, employers had to ensure that their revenue gains outpaced inflation rates now in the double digits.
--p. 176
And, of course, that proved impossible.

Just how bad was unemployment in the '70s and early '80s?

Well, "Unemployment, which had held at under 4 percent through . . . the late 1960s, went to 5 percent and then 6 percent in 1970 and 1971" (p. 93). "[I]t surged to 9 percent in 1975, easily the highest level since the Depression, a rate that was one-quarter higher than during any postwar recession" (p. 105). "Unemployment hovered at 6 percent in 1978 and 1979 and went to 7 percent in 1980" (pp. 175-176).

Back in the 1960s, Arthur Okun, chairman of President Johnson's Council of Economic Advisors, had almost jokingly produced what he called the "economic discomfort index" (the sum of the inflation rate and unemployment rate--a play on the weather service's "discomfort index" that totals temperature and humidity). In the '60s, Okun's index ran at 6 or 7. "[I]n 1975 it hit an unthinkable 18." And, as Domitrovic says, "This wasn't merely discomfort, so someone recast the metric as the 'misery index'" (p. 105).

"The misery index, at 21 in 1980 thanks to inflation at 14 and unemployment at 7, was 16 in 1982. Eight points of inflation had been traded for three of unemployment." Unemployment actually hit 9.7 percent in 1982 (p. 231). [Let me note--as Domitrovic does--that 1982 was the second year of Reagan's presidency. Not to make excuses for him (Domitrovic, ever the historian, points out several strategic and tactical mistakes Reagan and his advisors--not to mention Congress--made), but it is worth noting here that, following the screaming inflation of the late '70s and 1980 (immediately prior to Reagan's taking office),
The consumer price index rose [only] 3.4 percent (annualized) in the last quarter of 1981, a remarkable achievement. (The full-year 1981 figure was still 10.3 percent.) In 1982, prices in the first quarter rose at an annual rate of only 2.1 percent before yielding to a full-year rate of 6.2 percent. Thus did 1982 end a three-year run of double-digit inflation.
--p. 231
We will return to the issues of inflation and unemployment--the misery index--at a future date, when we consider the results (or lack thereof) of the so-called "supply-side revolution."

Let us "merely" agree, here, that unemployment in the '70s and early '80s was a major problem--worse than at any point in United States' history except for the Great Depression (when, admittedly, it was much worse).

Let us admit, however, one additional point that Domitrovic wants us to acknowledge: when modern pundits claim that the present economic turmoil is unprecedented except for the Great Depression, they are, most definitely, talking without knowledge. The United States' unemployment rate in 2008 to 2010 is not so different from what it was in 1975 and 1982 . . . though those periods of high unemployment were accompanied by far worse inflation. The misery index was far worse than it is today or has been in the last two years or so since the economy started to falter.

9. Property taxes through the roof--and a tax revolt.

Despite all the talk about income taxes, Domitrovic says,
The tax that threatened to turn the '70s funk to the Great Depression was the property tax. In inflationary times, commodities, limited in supply by the earth, increase in price at a rate greater than inflation. . . . Commodities take on the monetary function surrendered by money . . . , that of the "storehouse of value." The one thing that is most limited in supply by the Earth is the earth itself--land. Land values can race far ahead of the price level in inflationary times. The effect is especially acute when the land in question is generally desirable: California land, for example.

In the 1970s, California land prices spiked enormously, just as gold, oil, gas, and other commodities did, but there was a difference in owning land as opposed to a commodity. There was no excise tax on gold, tungsten, copper, and so on, even if there came to be equivalents of such things on oil. There certainly was an excise on California land, namely the local property tax, which averaged about 2.7 percent through early 1978.

Ten years before, in 1968, if you had been a brave California home buyer who stretched your budget to take out a mortgage on a $50,000 home, the tax component of the monthly mortgage payment would've been about $110. Over the next ten years, as the assessors reacted to a fivefold increase in the value of the property, that component would have risen to $550 per month. Inflation had been about 100 percent, but tax inflation had been 500 percent. True, the mortgage would've been reduced in real size by inflation, but that implies that one actually keeps one's COLAs. Given bracket creep, one does not. The bottom line: by 1978, many Californians who had lived in their homes for years realized that they might soon face foreclosure.

Had nothing happened, it would've made for curious history. . . . But . . . California voters . . . passed Proposition 13 in June 1978. Prop 13 collapsed the property tax to 1 percent and underindexed it for future inflation. Henceforth the only time the tax code would treat a house according to its market value would be upon its sale.
--pp. 153-154

10. Government consuming an ever-increasing share of the nation's productive capacity and wealth.

Domitrovic speaks of this issue many times throughout the book, but this section expresses it very well.
[Treasury Secretary William] Simon's last act as treasury secretary, in January 1977, had been to issue a report calling for unconditional tax cuts, including a cut in the top rate of almost half. . . .

In early 1978, . . . Simon's [book] Time for Truth . . . reported . . . [that] government at all levels have benefited from greatly increased revenues in the 1970s because of inflation and bracket creep. Indeed, "the share of gross national product eaten up the government has been inflating feverishly," Simon reported. "In 1930, spending . . . accounted for 12 percent of the GNP. By 1976, as was 36 percent."

Simon marveled that, despite the transfer of wealth from the private sector to government, government was having an ever harder time making ends meet. One of the reasons the Carter deficits were unintelligible to Simon was that they persisted, then increased, in the face of rising tax revenues as a percentage of GDP--not to mention falling military spending. When deficits go up with increasing revenues, and do so consistently, the only expectation can be for further displacement of the real economy by government. Reflecting on this "cannibalistic pattern," Simon wrote that quote no economy can survive a structural war conducted against it by the state."
Finally, one last major problem from the 1970s.

11. Ever-increasing government intrusions into [formerly] private decisions.

A quick summary statement of the problem:
Throughout the long 1970s, the federal government of the United States preoccupied itself with such things as fixing prices, ushering labor unions not to take wage increases, begging shoppers to rein in their spending, mistaking nominal for real income in the tax code, adding regulations, . . . and . . .
We'll stop here with our summary of the worst economic problems of the 1970s in the United States.


*******

Next time: What is supply-side economics?

Sunday, April 04, 2010

The Terrible 1970s (Econoclasts, Part II)

#3 in an ongoing series on Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution and Restored American Prosperity. First post in the series: Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution, Intro. Previous post: "Supply-side" economics was a colossal failure, wasn't it?



Brian Domitrovic's Econoclasts is a history book from beginning to end. Considering my interests, I had to remind myself several times as I read it because I had a much narrower purpose, going in, than Domitrovic had for writing it.

Part I, a 99-page "Reconsideration of the 20th Century," summarizes American monetary policy from 1913, the year in which the income tax was instituted and the Federal Reserve created, till about 1974. It actually begins in 1974 and describes the sorry state of the American economy at that time, then flashes back to 1913 and tells the story in between.

The history is interesting--Domitrovic talks specifically of government policies throughout the 20th century with particular interest in the post-World War II period. The entire history, I think, is worth one's while. But my personal interests here in my blog are limited enough that I want to focus primarily on the 1970s and following.

So, if you don't mind, I would like to bring you back to the mid-70s.

I am 53. I was still 17 when I first left home and began my freshman year in college. I had turned 18 just a few weeks before OPEC, the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries, shut off the oil spigots in October 1973.

If you are my age or younger, you may not have strong memories of many of the worst ravages of the economic upheaval of the mid- to late 1970s. I was aware of the dramatic price increase in gasoline that occurred beginning in October of 1973, and I saw photographs and read about the long lines of cars waiting to be refueled . . . and of gasoline stations completely out of inventory, . . . but these events didn't affect me personally a whole lot . . . I imagine because . . . I was in college, . . . because I rarely drove a car, . . . because my living expenses, overall, were rather low, . . . and, finally, because I was single.

Again, I was aware of the galloping inflation and felt the pall of economic difficulties (although, looking back, I wonder how much I attributed the pall at the time to the emotional impact of living in central Michigan where the winters are cold and interminably gray).

One event that comes to mind: I remember one day being told that Michigan State University might run out of its coal supply . . . which, if it had occurred, would have meant we would have run out of heat, hot water, and much if not all of our electricity on campus. I remember watching the large pile of coal slowly diminish that winter and wondering if the coal would come in time.

Happily, it did.

Domitrovic brought me back and, whether it is due to my more advanced years or, perhaps, because I was actually more impacted than I thought, the data points he shared stirred up some fairly strong emotions.

Perhaps you remember some of the titles of popular books from that era: Paul Ehrlich and his Population Bomb, William and Paul Paddock’s Famine 1975!, the Limits to Growth report from the “Club of Rome,” Lester Thurow’s The Zero-Sum Society, the Christian end-of-the-world blockbuster, The Late Great Planet Earth by Hal Lindsay, . . . and others. I would say the era was surrounded by a general pessimism.

But besides the feelings, on a more practical level, Domitrovic mentions at least eight economic and political problems of the 1970s whose solutions were not clear:
  1. Price and wage inflation.
     
  2. Tax bracket creep.
     
  3. Financial stress for business owners.
     
  4. Effective capital gains taxes above 100%.
     
  5. A preference for "stuff" over saving.
     
  6. A preference for commodities and "stuff" over capital investment.
     
  7. Resource shortages or scarcities.
     
  8. Terrible unemployment.
     
  9. Property taxes through the roof--and a tax revolt.
     
  10. Government consuming an ever-increasing share of the nation's productive capacity and wealth.
     
  11. Ever-increasing government intrusions into [formerly] private decisions.
I'll try to summarize these briefly, the first four in this post, the last seven (which I felt I was able to summarize in shorter order) tomorrow.

1. Price and wage inflation.

Concerning price inflation:
[I]n October 1973, . . . the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) signaled that it would triple the price of oil. The "oil shock" would soon become most economists' convenient catchall explanation for the raging inflation, recessions, and stock-market plunge that characterized the economy in the late Nixon and Ford-Carter eras. But in reality, the inflation crisis was in full swing before the OPEC shock of late 1973. OPEC moved to raise prices precisely because the currency instability emanating from the United States was already troubling the world. In the 12 months before the OPEC announcement, consumer prices in the United States increased by 8 percent, breaking out of the 5 percent range established in Nixon's first term, a rate that itself was quadruple the historical norm. . . .

[T]here was one great commodity, of greater importance even than oil to daily life, whose price rose the most in 1973, transfixing the nation in disbelief. That's commodity was food, which suffered 15 percent inflation that year. Food became the first major commodity to burst out of the 5 percent inflation band and to goad the general index up to unseen levels, a leadership role later assumed by oil, gas, and various metals naturally be limited in supply. The inflation laggard in 1973 was transportation (the price of which increased 3 percent), making it logically impossible that rising "energy" costs were responsible for inflation at the grocery store.

Eggs went up 49 percent in 1972-73, pacing the category of poultry, meats, and fish, which rose 25 percent as a group.

--p. 104


[I]n the recession years of 1974 and 1975, consumer prices somehow increased at World War I rates--11 percent and 9 percent, respectively. At the end of 1975, the economy was only marginally bigger than it had been in 1973, and prices were 25 percent higher.

--p. 105

With respect to wage inflation, Domitrovic reminded me of a term I had pretty well forgotten: COLAs--cost-of-living-adjustments.

I believe it was during this period--the mid-'70s--that COLAs first became bargaining issues in union negotiations. Living in Michigan at the time, and with the auto industry and auto workers being such a large presence in the state's economy at the time, I was very aware of unions, union activities, and strikes. People elsewhere in the country, I'm sure, were also aware. There were a lot of labor actions taking place at the time!

And our presidents--first Nixon, with his staggering, unprecedented-in-peacetime "wage and price controls," then Ford, with his "WIN--Whip Inflation Now" campaign, and, finally, Carter, with his attempts to get labor unions and corporate managers voluntarily to agree not to permit wages or prices to increase more than 7 percent in a year-- . . . our presidents, too, were deeply concerned about galloping inflation.

In high price-inflation environments, you need major adjustments in your salary if you are to be able to buy this year the same amount of "stuff" as you did the year before. And so, as prices rose at astronomical rates, so did wages.

This rise, first in prices and then in wages, created a terrible effect that the federal government at first--and for many years--refused to address. It was the problem of . . .

2. Tax bracket creep.

Domitrovic explains:
By the late 1970s, everybody had become acquainted with . . . bracket creep, [a term that] referred to the progressivity of the tax code in combination with inflation. . . . Inflation ran at 7.5 percent per year, 45 percent total, from 1973 to 1978. If a worker making $19,000 in 1973 had cost-of-living adjustments (COLAs) equal to the rise in consumer prices, the worker was making about $27,500 after five years. In 1973, a worker making $19,000 had an income tax rate that topped out at 25 percent. Yet in 1978, the worker would have found that every dollar of his cumulative $8,500 raise--a raise that covered only his rise in living expenses--was taxed at higher rates. The first $4,000 was taxed at 28 percent, the next $4,000 at 32 percent, and the remaining dollars at 36 percent.

The COLA meant to keep the worker even with inflation, but it failed. For the COLA was additional income, and higher marginal rates applied to that additional income. To have been a real COLA, it should have been taxed at the average rate of tax for all the worker's income, in this case 17 percent. But that is not how a progressive tax system works. All new income is taxed at the highest rate an income earner is subject to. A COLA could even vault earners into a higher marginal rate bracket than that at which their last dollar of income, pre-COLA, was taxed. . . .

The numbers were grim. For our 1973 worker to have maintained the same standard of living against inflation, the worker would have had to arrange for something like $29,400 of income in 1978. That is, a 55 percent raise (8.7 percent per year) was required to keep up with inflation as it mixed with the tax code.

For most workers, this was unthinkable.

--pp. 150-151

Domitrovic references research by Paul Craig Roberts who was working for Orrin Hatch at the time. Roberts noted that someone whose average income tax rate was 10% needed a raise 11% above the rate of inflation (i.e., if inflation was 7%, he would need a 7.77% wage increase) just to stay even. Better-paid workers would need raises worth 40% or more above the rate of inflation (if inflation was running at 7%, the better-paid worker would require a raise of at least 9.28%) to stay even.

A syndicated columnist at the Boston Herald-American described the cases of specific workers whose real purchasing power went down as their wages increased. "A businessman named 'Lawrence K.,' . . . saw his income go up by half in ten years and his after-tax purchasing power [went] down by a third."

And if the average wage-earner felt pressure, consider the . . .

3. Financial stress for business owners.

Domitrovic writes:
Since the 45 percent inflation of 1973-78 required a 55 percent increase in salaries, firms seeking to give real COLAs to their employees faced cash-flow problems, if not the stalking horse of bankruptcy . . . (p. 152).

In [the] ten-year period [of 1973 to 1982], the steel wage rate climbed 179 percent, while inflation rose 132 percent. Unless there was supercharged productivity, raises of this order meant raids on business profits. And given the way depreciation was treated in the tax code, there was not supercharged productivity. The stock market took due note and encouraged the likes of U.S. Steel to bail out to commodities. (p. 176)
We'll be telling the story of U.S. Steel in a few moments. For now, let's discuss the problem of depreciation.

4. Effective capital gains taxes above 100%.

Early in his book, on page 13, to be exact, Domitrovic makes a comment that blew me away when I first read it. "No way!" I said to myself.
In the 1970s, income derived from work was being taxed at a particularly acute rate. So was entrepreneurialism (in the form of a capital-gains tax that in many cases, incredibly, exceeded 100 percent).
It took me a while to find the data to back up this claim. Domitrovic provides it on pages 132 to 134 as he references work by economist Norman Ture (too-RAY) in Ture's The Effects of Tax Policy on Capital Formation.
In one of Ture's examples, a business owner contemplated buying a piece of machinery for $1,000. Because the top bracket taxed income at 48 percent, this business, if run by a top earner who took a salary, would have to earn $1,923 to buy the machinery. Yet this was only the first step in the long gauntlet of taxation.

Ture assumed, generously, that the machinery would yield 12 percent per year in profits, or $156. This $156 would itself be dunned at tax time. Ture crunched the numbers and concluded that to make a profitable investment in capital equipment of $1,000, this business owner would have to commit $2,450 of pretax income. If the owner spent the money instead, all that would be required was the original $1,923. The effective tax penalty on investment in lieu of consumption for a business owner was $500 for each $2,000 invested--an absurdity.

Depreciation told an even sadder tale. . . . [D]epreciation schedules . . . were extended to a standard of thirteen years . . . in the 1970s. This was brutal. Inflation averaged 9 percent in the stagflation era. After thirteen years, 9 percent inflation means that an initial price is depreciated, in the end, to 33 percent. On a depreciation schedule, this requires that businesses he ducked less and less of the real purchase price of equipment every year, culminating in a deduction that is one-third of the equipment's real value. . . .

Another example: A [privately owned] company gains income less expenses of $1,000. The corporate income tax takes 48 percent and the rest is paid out as dividends to shareholders, who must pay [if they were in the top bracket at that time] 70 percent tax on that type of income. The $1,000 [corporate net income before taxes] first becomes, because of the corporate rate, $520 [corporate net income after taxes], then $156 [net income after taxes to top income bracket shareholders] because of the dividend rate; $844 goes to the IRS.
Okay. The federal government got 84.4 percent of the this hypothetical company's $1,000 income.

Let me simply note that at those kinds of rates, I'm not highly motivated to invest in my company.

But remember, Domitrovic claimed, back on p. 13, that capital gains taxes could often exceed 100%. How does he come up with that number?

He suggests we take the same company we just described and look at expenses.

To make his example more understandable, I am going to make up some numbers. I am not going to attempt to create an illustration that perfectly matches the tax codes of the '60s and '70s/ I am simply trying to illustrate the general principle.

Suppose the company we just described had purchased a machine 13 years before that, at the time, cost $20,000. Now suppose, after 13 years, the company still had $1,000 of the original $20,000 purchase price to write off as depreciation. . . . --Here's where things get interesting.

Keep in mind that there was a lot--a lot--of inflation over the course of the 13 years since the company purchased that equipment! In current money, the machine that cost $20,000 13 years ago would now cost $60,000. I.e., every $1,000 of the original price should "really" be counted as $3,000 in today's money!

Therefore,
[I]f inflation had denuded the depreciation allowance by, say, two-thirds [i.e., the $1,000 depreciation allowance was worth one-third of what it "should" have been had the original $20,000 been valued at $60,000 in today's inflated currency--JAH]. . . , the real depreciation allowance should have been $3,000. [And i]f depreciation schedules . . . had been indexed for inflation, the company would have not reported a profit of $1,000, but a loss of $2,000, on account of a proper depreciation allowance of $3,000.

We have, in this case, a company and its owners paying $844 in taxes on a loss of $2,000.

--p. 133

That is a specific example of a single imaginary company's owners' predicament. On an aggregate (economy-wide) level, economist Martin Feldstein of Harvard wrote in the Wall Street Journal (July 27, 1978), "We found that in 1973 individuals paid capital-gains tax on $4.6 billion of nominal capital gains on corporate stock. When the costs of these shares are adjusted for the increase in the consumer price level since they were purchased, this gain becomes a loss of nearly $1 billion. The $4.6 billion of nominal capital gains resulted in a tax liability of $1.1 billion."

Domitrovic comments,
Feldstein found that only about half of the $1.1 billion in capital-gains tax revenue that went to the federal government was taken from investments that had made money in real terms. The other half had been taken from investments that merely kept up with inflation, in whole or in part. "Many individuals paid a substantial capital-gains tax," Feldstein wrote, "even though, when adjustment is made for the change in the price level, the actually receive less from their sale than they had originally paid."
Most disturbing according to Feldstein: "The mismeasurement of capital gains is most severe for taxpayers with incomes under $100,000" (p. 163).

Domitrovic multiplies these examples. The point, however is this: Anyone with the ability to invest in the stock market--i.e., anyone with the means to provide capital for start-up companies--realizes that it is all but impossible to come out ahead when inflation is galloping along and you'll be taxed not only on your investment's real returns but on the phantom "gains" of inflation.

With capital investments being taxed at such high rates, people who had money to invest did the only reasonable thing they could do in such circumstances: they invested in tangible assets rather than stocks and bonds. Put another way, the '70s saw . . .

5. A preference for "stuff" over saving.

. . . --To be continued tomorrow.

Monday, March 29, 2010

Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution, Intro

As I noted back on February 19th, I received an e-mail from the Intercollegiate Studies Institute with a sidelink to a brief (36:48) lecture by Dr. Brian Domitrovic, assistant professor of history at Sam Houston State University in Huntsville, Texas. I was so impressed by Dr. Domitrovic’s presentation that I ordered a copy of his book, Econoclasts: The Rebels Who Sparked the Supply-Side Revolution and Restored American Prosperity.

The book turned out to be, in many ways, much more than I bargained for, but I finally finished it on Saturday, and I'm glad I took the time!

I read the book because I was hoping to understand what the "supply-side revolution" was really all about: What did the proponents believe? How did they argue their case? and What were the results? I got all those things, for sure, but I also read way more details than I really wanted to take the time for, including lots and lots of names (along with brief biographical sketches), and article titles, and journal paper summaries, and descriptions of cocktail parties, and narratives about the personal feelings of participants at various points. Just "more than I wanted to know."

Still. Domitrovic wrote the book in hopes of filling a void. As he writes in his concluding chapter:
Economic crises caused by loose money and high taxes were cured by [supply-side] policy mix[es] in 1922, 1962, and 1981. Likewise, similarly caused crises that did not call forth the [supply-side] response--the recessions of 1969-70 and 1974-75--festered until the proper cure came.

There is not one word of historical scholarship on any of this. . . . In academic history, the secondary literature on supply-side economics is nil. Many things have been written about supply-side economics, but none of them falls in the category of "literature" as the term is used by historians.

Econoclasts, p. 292

Domitrovic notes that this lack of historical research has some serious (negative) practical implications for those of us alive today. (And I'm talking about today, in 2010.
[A]s the economic crisis deepened in 2008 and 2009, public officials were quick to compare it with the 1930s. It was as if the Great Depression were the only economic crisis, and the New Deal the only solution, they had ever heard of. How could it have been otherwise? What serious books could be read, what courses taken, on the new vehicles of economic stabilization that had been pioneered since JFK's time? Economists tracked this history to some degree, but their specialty is still distance and models. Documenting what policymakers did in the past, and why, is a job for historians.

What might history teach President Obama and the favorably inclined Congress he enjoys? First, it is time to understand what great Democrats achieved in the past. It is difficult to believe that had FDR honored George Washington's precedent and not sought a third term, he would be regarded today as anything short of a grand failure. The recession that started right after FDR's reelection in 1936 canceled all gains made by the New Deal and perpetuated the Great Depression until the clouds of war came. For all the make-work programs of the Works Progress Administration and the crusades against big business, the New Deal in its classic--1933-39--did nothing to restore prosperity.

JFK, in contrast, took all the right advice and knew when and how to defy it. His ambition was such that he was going to have spectacular growth on his watch, no matter whom he had cut deals with--even if that meant the Chamber of Commerce and Ford Motor, as opposed to this orders of the neoclassical synthesis who made up his Council of Economic Advisors. . . .

JFK's is the result Obama should aspire to, not FDR's.

Econoclasts, pp. 292-293

Domitrovic urges five specific policy recommendations. I intend to return to them in a future post after I have summarized some of the content of the book that most impressed me.

This post is merely to "forewarn" you of subject matter I hope to deal with in the days to come.

I hope you find it interesting and, perhaps, inspirational!


Next post in this series: "Supply-side" economics was a colossal failure, wasn't it?